Monday, May 20, 2019

Agency Costs and Corporate Governance Mechanisms

sureness cost and merged nerve mechanicss Evidence for UK ho affairholds Chrisostomos Florackis and Aydin Ozkan* University of York, UK Abstract In this paper, we aim to extend the experimental literature on the determinants of execution of instrument be by using a bear-sized ingest of UK listed stiffs. To do so, we implement devil utility(a) proxies for style cost the proportion of pith sales to extreme pluss (addition swage rate) and the balance of selling, worldwide and administrative costs (SG&A) to total sales. In our compendium, we control for the influence of or so(prenominal)(prenominal)(prenominal) cozy governance machines or devices that were unattended by previous studies.Also, we shew the potential interactions amidst these mechanisms and pixilated issue opportunities in find delegation costs. Our results reveal that the crownwork social organisation characteristics of firms, namely bank debt and debt maturity, constitute ii of the most important bodily governance devices for UK companies. Also, managerial will power, managerial compensation and will power conpenny dimensionn seem to feed an important employment in mitigating elbow room costs. Fin completelyy, our results project that the advert upholded by internal governance mechanisms on force costs varies with firms ripening opportunities.JEL classification G3 G32 Keywords Agency costs Growth opportunities Internal Corporate Governance Mechanisms. * Corresponding author. section of Economics and Related Studies, University of York, Heslington, York, YO10 5DD, UK. Tel. + 44 (1904) 434672. Fax + 44 (1904) 433759. E-mail emailprotected ac. uk. We thank seminar participants at University of York, and the 2004 European finance Association Meetings for facilitateful comments and suggestions. 1 1. Introduction Fol humbleding Jensen and Meckling (1976), authorization relations within the firm and costs associated with them drive been extensively in vestigated in the in unified finance literature.There is a great deal of falsifiable spiel providing show up that financial decisions, investment decisions and, hence, firm look upon atomic number 18 signifi prattly affected by the battlefront of confidence conflicts and the extent of office costs. The think of these studies has been the squeeze of the haveed sanction costs on the writ of execution of firms. 1 Moreover, the implicit assumption is that, in imperfect large(p) market places, berth costs arising from conflicts amid firms claimholders last and the measure of firms decreases if the market take overs that these costs argon likely to be realised.It is akinly assumed that at that place be internal and external corporate governance mechanisms that can help press the pass judgment costs and their invalidating impact on firm take to be. For example, much of prior work on the self-control and performance birth relies on the public opinion that ma nagerial self-control can align the sakes of managers and sh beholders and hence one would observe a electro absolute impact exerted by managerial dealholdings on the performance of firms. The substantiative impact is argued to be cod to the decrease in the expected costs of the agency conflict betwixt managers and sh beholders.Despite much valuable insights fork upd by this strand of literature, however, moreover very few studies directly tackle the measurement issue of the principal covariant of interest, namely agency costs. Notable exceptions atomic number 18 Ang et al. (2000) and shrink and Davidson (2003), which investigate the a posteriori determinants of agency costs and conpennyrate on the role of debt and ownership structure in mitigating agency puzzles for the US firms. In doing so, they employ deuce substitute(a) proxies for agency costs the symmetry of total sales to total pluss ( summation overturn) and the balance of selling, general and administr ative expenses (SG&A) to total sales.In overseas telegram with the lookings of prior research they provide try for the view that managerial ownership aligns the interests of managers and shargonholders and, hence, reduces agency costs in general. However, there is no consensus on the role of debt in mitigating such(prenominal)(prenominal) puzzles and associated costs. Ang et al. (2000) bloom tabu that debt has an all toldeviating role whereas Sign and Davidson (2003) an aggravating one. The objective of this paper is to extend the investigation of these studies by analysing empirically the determinants of agency costs in the UK for a large stress of 1See, for example, Morck et al. (1988) McConnell and Servaes (1990) and Agrawal and Knoeber (1996) among others. 2 listed firms. Fol woefuling the works of Ang et al. (2000) and, Sign and Davidson (2003), we standarding both proxies of agency costs addition employee turnover and the (SG&A) ratio. More specifically, we empirica lly dissect the impact of capital structure, ownership, get on bit and managerial compensation on the costs likely to uprise from agency conflicts in the midst of managers and sh areholders. In doing so, we in any case pay particular attention to the role of growth opportunities in influencing the dominance of internal governance mechanisms in decrease agency costs. In carrying come in the epitome in this paper, we aim to provide insights at least in three important areas of the empirical research on agency costs. First, in investigating the determinants of agency costs, the epitome of this paper incorporates important firmspecific characteristics (internal corporate governance devices) that possibly affect agency costs but were ignored by previous studies.For example, we search the role the debt maturity structure of firms can maneuver in controlling agency costs. It is widely acknowledged that short debt may be much efficient than long-term debt in reducing the expected costs of the underinvestment puzzle of Myers (1977). 3 Accordingly, in our analysis, we analyze the maturity structure of debt as a potential governance device that is effective in reducing the expected costs of the agency conflict mingled with shareholders and debtholders. Similar to Ang et al. 2000) that investigate if bank debt creates a absolute externality in the form of lower agency costs, we also check if the source of debt financing matters in mitigating agency problems. A nonher potentially effective corporate governance mechanism we consider relates to managerial compensation. late studies suggest that compensation contracts can motivate managers to adopt actions that maximize shareholders wealth (see, e. g. , Core et al. , 2001 Murphy, 1999 among others). This is based on the view that financial carrots motivate managers to maximize firm care for.That is, a manager leave presumably be slight likely, ceteris paribus, to exert light effort and essay the loss of his job the greater the direct of his compensation. several(prenominal) empirical studies provide narrate for the effectiveness of managerial compensation as a corporate governance mechanism. For instance, 2 As explained later in the paper, the two proxies for agency costs that are exercised in our analysis are to a greater extent likely to catch up with the agency problems amid managers and shareholders. However, we do non become come out out the possibility that they may also capture the agency problems between shareholders and debtholders. It is argued that firm with greater growth opportunities should have more short-run debt because shortening debt maturity would make it more likely that debt give lift outride before any opportunity to exercise the growth options. Consistent with this prediction, there are several empirical debt maturity studies that experience a forbid relation between maturity and growth opportunities (see, e. g. , Barclay and Smith, 1995 Guedes and Opler, 1996 and Ozkan, 2000 among others). 3 Hutchinson and Gul (2004) find that managers compensation can moderate the banish association between growth opportunities and firm value.In this paper, we examine the effectiveness of managerial compensation as a corporate governance mechanism by including the salary of managers in our empirical representative. We also acknowledge that there have been concerns well-nigh excessive compensation encases and their shun impact on corporate performance. Accordingly, we investigate the possibility of a non-mo nononic impact the managerial compensation may exert on agency costs. Second, our empirical model captures potential interactions between corporate governance mechanisms and growth opportunities.Following McConnell and Servaes (1995) and Lasfer (2002), we expect the effectiveness of governance mechanisms in reducing agency problems to be dependent on firms growth opportunities. In particular, if agency problems are ass ociated with greater tuition asymmetry (a common problem in gamy-growth firms), we expect the effectiveness of corporate governance mechanisms in mitigating asymmetric information problems to increase in spirited-growth firms (Smith and Watts, 1992 and Gaver and Gaver, 1993).However, if, as argued by Jensen (1986), agency problems are associated with conflicts over the use of unfreeze cash flow (a common problem in low-growth firms), we expect governance mechanisms that are likely to mitigate such problems to play a more important role in low-growth firms (Jensen, 1986). Last but not least, in contrast to previous studies that focus on the US market, we provide recite for UK firms. Although the UK and the US are ordinarily modifyd as having a akin common law regulatory system (see, e. g. , La Porta et al. 1998), the UK market bears crocked distinguishing characteristics. 4 It is argued that several of these characteristics may contribute to a more earthshaking degree of m anagerial discretion and, hence, higher level of managerial agency costs. For example, despite the relatively high proportion of shares held by financial institutions, there is a great deal of evidence that financial investors do not take an active role in corporate governance. Similarly, UK boards are usually characterized as corporate devices that provide weak disciplinary function.More specifically, weak fiduciary obligations on managing directors have resulted in non administrators playing more an advisory than a observe role. 5 Consequently, the investigation of agency issues and the effectiveness of the preference governance 4 For a more detailed discussion about the characteristics of the prevailing UK corporate governance system see trivial and Keasey (1999) Faccio and Lasfer (2000) Franks et al. (2001) and Ozkan and Ozkan (2004). 5 Empirical studies by Faccio and Lasfer (2000), Goergen and Rennebog (2001), Franks et al. 2001) and Short and Keasey (1999) provide evidenc e on the weak role of institutions and board of directors in reducing agency problems in the UK. 4 mechanisms in the UK, in a period that witnesses an intensive discussion of corporate governance issues, would be of significant importance. Our results potently suggest that managerial ownership constitutes a rugged corporate governance mechanism for the UK firms. This result is arranged with the findings provided by Ang et al. (2000) and Sign and Davidson (2003) for the US firms.Ownership concentration and salary also seem to play a significant role in mitigating agency think problems. The results concerning the role of capital structure variable stars on agency costs are striking. It seems that both the source and the maturity structure of corporate debt have a significant effect on agency costs. Finally, there is unassailable evidence that specific governance mechanisms are not homogeneous but vary with growth opportunities. For instance, we find that decision maker ownership is more effective as a governance mechanism for high-growth firms.This result is complementary to the results obtained by Smith and Watts (1992), Gaver and Gaver (1993) and Lasfer (2002), which stake the view that high-growth firms are likely to prefer bonus mechanisms (e. g. managerial ownership) whereas low-growth firms focus more on monitoring mechanisms (e. g. short-term debt). The remainder of the paper is organized as follows. In section 2 we discuss the associate to hypothesis and formulate our empirical hypotheses. Section 3 describes the way in which we have inventioned our sample and presents several descriptive statistics of that.Section 4 presents the results of our univariate, multivariate and sensitivity analysis. Finally, section 5 concludes. 2. Agency costs and Governance Mechanisms In what follows, we will discuss the potential interactions between agency costs and internal corporate governance mechanisms available to firms. Also, we will analyze how firm gro wth opportunities affect agency costs and the birth between governance mechanism and agency costs. 2. 1 Debt Financing Agency problems within a firm are usually related to free cash-flow and asymmetric information problems (see, for example, Jensen, 1986 and Myers and Majluf, 1984).It is widely acknowledged that debt servicing obligations help reduce of agency problems of this sort. This is particularly true for the matter of privately held debt. For example, bank 5 debt incorporates significant taperling characteristics that can mitigate informational asymmetry conflicts between managers and outside investors (Jensen, 1986 Stulz, 1990 and Ross, 1977). In particular, the announcement of a bank credit agreement conveys positive news to the fall market about creditors worthiness.Bank debt also bears important renegotiation characteristics. As Berlin and Mester (1992) argue, because banks are well informed and typically smaller in number, renegotiation of a loan is easier. A bank s willingness to renegotiate and renew a loan manoeuvres the being of a good kindred between the borrower and the creditor and that is a further good signal about the quality of the firm. Moreover, it is argued that bank debt has an advantage in comparison to publicly traded debt in monitoring firms activities and in collecting and processing information.For example, Fama (1985) argues that bank loaners have a comparative advantage in minimizing information costs and getting access to information not otherwise publicly available. Therefore, banks can be viewed as performing a screening role employing private information that leads them to evaluate and monitor borrowers more effectively than other lenders. In addition to debt source, the maturity structure of debt may matter. For example, short-term debt may be more useful than long-term debt in reducing free cash flow problems and in signalling high quality to outsiders.For example, as Myers (1977) suggests, agency conflicts be tween managers and shareholders such as the underinvestment problem can be curtailed with short-term debt. Flannery (1986) argues that firms with large potential information asymmetries are likely to issue short-term debt because of the larger information costs associated with long-term debt. Also, short-term debt can be advantageous especially for high-quality companies due to its low refinancing risk (Diamond, 1991). Finally, if production curve is downward sloping, issuing short-term debt increases firm value (Brick and Ravid, 1985).Consequently, bank debt and short-term debt are expected to constitute two important corporate governance devices. We involve the ratio of bank debt to total debt and the ratio of short-term debt to total debt to our empirical model so as to approximate the lenders competency to mitigate agency problems. Also, we include the ratio of total debt to total pluss (leverage) to approximate lenders inducing to monitor. In general, as leverage increases , so does the risk of default by the firm, hence the incentive for the lender to monitor the firm6. 6 Ang et al. 2000) focus on sample of small firms, which have do not have easy access to public debt, and examine the impact of bank debt on agency costs. On the contrary, Sign and Davidson (2003) focus on a sample of large firms, which have easy access to public debt, and examine the impact of public debt on 6 2. 2 Managerial Ownership The conflicts of interest between managers and shareholders arise mainly from the separation between ownership and control. Corporate governance deals with finding ways to reduce the order of magnitude of these conflicts and their adverse personal set up on firm value.For instance, Jensen and Meckling (1976) suggest that managerial ownership can align the interest between these two different groups of claimholders and, therefore, reduce the total agency costs within the firm. According to their model, the affinity between managerial ownership and age ncy costs is linear and the optimal point for the firm is achieved when the managers acquires all of the shares of the firm. However, the family between managerial ownership and agency costs can be non-monotonic (see, for example, Morck et al. , 1988 McConnel and Servaes, 1990,1995 and, Short and Keasey, 1999).It has been shown that, at low levels of managerial ownership, managerial ownership aligns managers and outside shareholders interests by reducing managerial incentives for perk consumption, manipulation of insufficient effort and engagement in nonmaximizing projects (alignment effect). by and by some level of managerial ownership, though, managers exert insufficient effort (e. g focus on external activities), collect private benefits (e. g. build empires or jazz perks) and entrench themselves (e. g. harness high risk projects or bend over backwards to resist a putsch) at the expense of other investors (entrenchment effect).Therefore the descent between the two is non-li near. The ultimate effect of managerial ownership on agency costs depends upon the trade-off between the alignment and entrenchment effects. In the context of our analysis we propose a non-linear race between managerial ownership and managerial agency costs. However, theory does not shed much light on the exact nature of the relationship between the two and, hence, we do not know which of the effects will dominate the other and at what levels of managerial ownership.We, therefore, carry out a preliminary investigation about the pattern of the relationship between managerial ownership and agency costs. Figure 1 presents the way in which the two variables are associated. Insert Figure 1 here agency costs. Our make is more equivalent to that of Ang et al (2000) given that UK firms use significant standards of bank debt financing (see Corbett and Jenkinson, 1997). 7 Clearly, at low levels of managerial ownership, asset turnover and managerial ownership are positively related. Howeve r, after managerial ownership exceeds the 10 per cent level, the relationship turns from positive to negative.A third turning point is that of 30 portion after which the relationship seems to turn to positive again. Consequently, there is evidence both for the alignment and the entrenchment effects in the sequel of our sample. In order to capture both of them in our empirical specification, we include the level, the foursquarely and the square of managerial ownership in our model as predictors of agency costs. 2. 3 Ownership niggardness A third alternative for alleviating agency problems is through concentrated ownership.Theoretically, shareholders could take themselves an active role in monitoring management. However, given that the monitoring benefits for shareholders are proportionate to their righteousness bet (see, for example, Grossman and Hart, 1988), a small or average shareholder has little or no incentives to exert monitoring behaviour. In contrast, shareholders with substantial stakes have more incentives to supervise management and can do so more effectively (see Shleifer and Vishny, 1986 Shleifer and Vishny, 1997 and accomplice and Lang, 1988).In general, the higher the amount of shares that investors hold, the stronger their incentives to monitor and, hence, protect their investment. Although large shareholders may help in the reduction of agency problems associated with managers, they may also harm the firm by causing conflicts between large and minority shareholders. The problem usually arises when large shareholders gain nearly full control of a corporation and engage themselves in self-dealing expropriation procedures at the expense of minority shareholders (Shleifer and Vishny, 1997).Also, as Gomez (2000) points out, these expropriation incentives are stronger when corporate governance of public companies insulates large shareholders from takeover threats or monitoring and the legal system does not protect minority shareholders becaus e either of poor laws or poor enforcement of laws. Furthermore, the existence of concentrated holdings may decrease diversification, market liquidation and stocks superpower to grow and, therefore, increase the incentives of large shareholders to expropriate firms resources. some(prenominal) empirical studies provide evidence consistent with that view (see, for example, Beiner et al, 2003). In order to streak the impact of ownership concentration on agency costs, we include a variable that refers to the sum of stakes of shareholders with rightfulness stake greater than 3 8 per cent in our regression equation. The results remain robust when the threshold value changes from 3 per cent to 5 per cent or 10 per cent. 2. 4 Board of Directors Corporate governance research recognizes the essential role performed by the board of directors in monitoring management (Fama and Jensen, 1983 Weisbach, 1988 and Jensen, 1993).The effectiveness of a board as a corporate governance mechanism depen ds on its size and composition. Large boards are usually more powerful than small boards and, hence, considered necessary for organizational effectiveness. For instance, as Pearce and Zahra (1991) point out, large powerful boards help in strengthening the necktie between corporations and their environments, provide counsel and advice regarding strategic options for the firm and play crucial role in creating corporate identity. Other studies, though, suggest that large boards are less effective than large boards.The underlying notion is that large boards make coordination, communication and decision-making more cumbersome than it is in smaller groups. Recent studies by Yermack, 1996 Eisenberg et al. , 1998 and Beiner et al, 2004 support such a view empirically. The composition of a board is also important. There are two dowrys that characterize the independence of a board, the proportion of non-executive directors and the separated or not roles of chief executive officer (chief ope rating officer) and death chair of the board (COB).Boards with a significant proportion of non-executive directors can limit the exercise of managerial discretion by exploiting their monitoring ability and protecting their reputations as effective and independent decision makers. Consistent with that view, Byrd and Hickman (1992) and Rosenstein and Wyatt (1990) propose a positive relationship between the percentage of non-executive directors on the board and corporate performance. Lin et al. (2003) also propose a positive share price reaction to the appointment of outside directors, especially when board ownership is low and the appointee possesses strong ex ante monitoring incentives.Along a slightly different dimension, Dahya et al. (2002) find that top-manager turnover increases as the fraction of outside directors increases. Other studies find exactly the opposite results. They argue that non-executive directors are usually characterized by lack of information about the firm, do not bring the requisite skills to the job and, hence, prefer to play a less confrontational role quite an than a more critical monitoring one (see, for example, Agrawal and Knoeker, 1996 Hermalin 9 nd Weisbach, 1991, and Franks et al. , 2001)7. As far as the separation between the role of chief operating officer and COB is concerned, it is believed that separated roles can lead to better board performance and, hence, less agency conflicts. The Cadbury (1992) radical on corporate governance stretches that issue and recommends that CEO and COB should be two distinct jobs. Firms should harmonize with the recommendation of the report for their own benefit. A decision not to combine these roles should be publicly explained.Empirical studies by Vafeas and Theodorou (1998), and Weir et al. (2002), though, which study that issue for the case of the UK market, provide results that do not support Cadburys stance that the CEO COB duality is undesirable. In the context of the UK market, UK boards are believed to be less effective than the US ones. For instance,. To test the effectiveness of the board of directors in mitigating agency problems we include three variables in our empirical model a) the ratio of the number of non-executive directors to he number of total directors, b) the total number of directors (board size) and c) a dummy variable which takes the value of 1 when the roles of CEO and COB are not separated and 0 otherwise. 2. 5 Managerial compensation Another important component of corporate governance is the compensation package that is provided to firm management. Recent studies by Core et al. (2001) and Murphy (1999) suggest, among others, that compensation contracts, whose use has been increased dramatically during the 90s, can motivate managers to take actions that maximize shareholders wealth.In particular, as Core et al. (2001) point out, if shareholders could directly observe the firms growth opportunities and executives actions no incentives would be necessary. However, due to asymmetric information between managers and shareholders, both truth and compensation related incentives are required. For example, an increase in managerial compensation may reduce managerial agency costs in the sense that satisfied managers will be less likely, ceteris paribus, to utilize insufficient effort, perform expropriation behaviour and, hence, risk the loss of their job.Despite the central importance of the issue, only a few empirical studies examine the impact of managerial compensation components on corporate performance. For example, Jensen and Murthy 7 Such a result may be consistent with the governance system prevailing in the UK market given the fact that UK legislation encourages non-executive directors to be passive since it does not impose fiduciary obligations on them. Also, UK boards are dominated by executive directors, which have less monitoring power.Franks et al. (2001) confirm this view by providing evidence on a non- disciplinary role of nonexecutive directors in the UK. 10 (1990) find a statistically significant relationship between the level of pay and performance. Murphy (1995), finds that the form, rather than the level, of compensation is what motivates managers to increase firm value. In particulars, he argues that firm performance is positively related to the percentage of executive compensation that is equity based.More recently, Hutchinson and Gul (2004) analyze whether or not managers compensation can moderate the negative association between growth opportunities and firm value8. The results of this study indicate that corporate governance mechanisms such as managerial lucre, managerial ownership and non-executive directors possibly affect the linkages between organizational environmental factors (e. g. growth opportunities) and firm performance.Finally, Chen (2003) analyzes the relationship between equity value and employees bonus. He finds that the annual stock bonus is strongly as sociated with the firms contemporaneous but not future performance. Managerial compensation, though, is considered to be a debated component of corporate governance. Despite its potentially positive impact on firm value, compensation may also work as an infectious greed which creates an environment ripe for abuse, especially at significantly high levels.For instance, remuneration packages usually include extreme benefits for managers such as the use of private jet, golf ball club membership, entertainment and other expenses, apartment purchase etc. Benefits of this sort usually cause abominable agency conflicts between managers and shareholders. 9 Therefore, it is mathematical that the relationship between compensation and agency costs is non-monotonic. Similar to the case of managerial ownership, we carry out a preliminary investigation about the pattern of the relationship between salary and agency costs.As shown in figure 2, the relationship between salary and agency costs is likely to be non-linear10. In our empirical model, we include the ratio of the total salary paid to executive directors to total assets as a determinant of agency costs. Also, in order to capture potential 8 Rather, the majority of the studies in that strand of literature reverse the causation and examine the impact of performance changes on executive or CEO compensation (see, for example, Rayton, 2003 among others). Concerns about excessive compensation packages and their negative impact on corporate performance have lead to the establishment of rudimentary recommendations in the form of best drills in which firms should postdate so as the problem with excessive compensation to be diminished. In the case of the UK market, for example, one of the basic recommendations of the Cadbury (1992) report was the establishment of an independent compensation committee. Also, in a posterior report, the Greenbury (1995) report, specific propositions about remuneration issues were made.For e xample, an issue that was stretched was the rate of increase in managerial compensation. In the case of the US market, the set of best practises includes, among others, the establishment of a compensation committee so as transparency and disclosure to be guaranteed (same practise an in the UK) and the substitution of stock options as compensation components with other tools that promote the long-term value of the high society 10 A similar preliminary analysis is carried out so as to check potential non-linearities concerning the relationship between the rest of internal governance mechanisms and agency costs.Our results (not account) indicate that none of them is related to agency costs in a non-linear way. 11 non-linearities, we include higher ordered salary monetary value in the regression equation. Finally, we include a dummy variable, which takes the value of 1 when a firm pays options or bonuses to managers and 0 otherwise. Including that dummy variable in our analysis enabl es us to test whether or not options and bonuses themselves provide incentives to managers.As grub (2001) points out, ignoring options is likely to incur serious problems unless managerial options are either negligible compared to ownership or nearly perfectly jibe with ownership. Insert Figure 2 here 2. 6 Growth Opportunities The magnitude of agency costs related to underinvestment, asset substitution and free cash flow differ significantly across high-growth and low-growth firms. In the underinvestment problem, managers may decide to pass up positive net present value projects since the benefits would mainly accrue to debt-holders.This is more severe for firms with more growth-options (Myers, 1977). Asset substitution problems, which occur when managers opportunistically substitute higher variant assets for low sectionalisation assets, are also more prevalent in high-growth firms due to information asymmetry between investors and borrowers (Jensen and Meckling, 1976). High-gro wth firms, though, verbalism lower free cashlow problems, which occur when firms have substantial cash reserves and a tendency to undertake risky and usually negative NPV investment projects (Jensen, 1986). presumption the different magnitude and types of agency costs between high-growth and low-growth firms, we expect the effectiveness of corporate governance mechanisms to vary with growth opportunities. In particular, if agency problems are associated with greater underinvestment or information asymmetry (a common problem in high-growth firms), we expect corporate governance mechanisms that mitigate these kinds of problems to be more effective in high-growth firms (Smith and Watts, 1992 and Gaver and Gaver, 1993).However, if, as argued by Jensen (1986), agency problems are associated with conflicts over the use of free cash flow (a common problem in low-growth firms), we expect governance mechanisms that mitigate such problems to play a more important role in low-growth firms (Je nsen, 1986). Several empirical studies that model union performance confirm the existence of potential interactions between internal governance mechanism and growth opportunities. For example, McConnell and Servaes (1995) find that the relationship between firm value and leverage is negative for high-growth firms and positive for low12 growth firms.Their results also indicate that equity ownership matters, and the way in which it matters depends upon investment opportunities. Specifically, they provide weak evidence that on the view that the assignation of equity ownership between corporate insiders and other types of investors is more important in low-growth firms. Also, Lasfer (2002) points out that high-growth firm (low-growth firms) rely more on managerial ownership (board structure) to mitigate agency problems. Finally, Chen (2003) finds that the positive relationship between annual stock bonus and equity value is stronger for firms with greater growth opportunities.In order to capture potential interaction effects, we include interaction terms between proxies for growth opportunities and governance mechanisms in our empirical model and, also, employ sample- riptideting methods (see, for example, McConnell and Servaes, 1995 and Lasfer, 2002). Based on previous empirical evidence the prediction we make is that mechanisms that are utilise to mitigate asymmetric information problems (free cash flow problems) are stronger in high-growth firms (low-growth firms). 3. Data and methodological analysis 3. 1 Data For our empirical analysis of agency costs we use a large sample of ublicly traded UK firms over the period 1999-2003. We use two data sources for the compilation of our sample. Accounting data and data on the market value of equity are collected from Datastream database. Specifically, we use Datastream to collect information for firm size, market value of equity, annual sales, selling general and administrative expenses, level of bank debt, short-term debt and total debt. nurture on firms ownership, board and managerial compensation structure is derived from the Hemscott Guru Academic Database.This database provides financial data for the UKs top 300,000 companies, detailed data on all directors of UK listed companies, live regulatory and AFX News feeds and share price charts and trades. Specifically, we get detailed information on the level of managerial ownership, ownership concentration, size and composition of the board, managerial salary, bonus, options and other benefits. Despite the fact that data on directors are provided in a spreadsheet format, information for each item is given in a separate file. This makes data collection for the required variables fairly complicated.For example, in order to get information about the amount of shares held by executive directors we have to combine two different files a) the 13 file that contains data on the amount of shares held by each director and b) the file that provides inform ation about the type of each directorship (e. g. executive director vs. nonexecutive director). Also, we have to take into line the fact that several directors in the UK hold positions in more than one company. Complications also arise when we sweat to collect information about the composition of the board and the remuneration package that is provided to executive directors.The way in which our final sample is compiled is the following we start with a total of 1672 UK listed firms derived from Datastream. This number reduces to 1450 firms after excluding financial firms from the sample. After matching Datastream data with the data provided by Hemscott, the number of firms further decreases to 1150. Missing firm course observations for any variable in the model during the sample period are also dropped. Finally, we exclude outliers so as to avoid the problem with extreme value. We end up with 897 firms for our empirical analysis. 3. Dependent Variable In our analysis we use two alt ernative proxies to measure agency costs. Firstly, we use the ratio of annual sales to total assets (Asset Turnover) as an rearward placeholder for agency costs. This ratio can be interpreted as an asset utilization ratio that shows how effectively management deploys the firms assets. For instance, a low asset turnover ratio may indicate poor investment decisions, insufficient effort, consumption of perquisites and purchase of unproductive products (e. g. office space). Firms with low asset turnover ratios are expected to experience high agency costs between managers and shareholders11.A similar placeholder for agency costs is also used in the studies of Ang et al. (2000) and Sign and Davidson (2003). However, Ang et al. (2000), instead of using the ratio directly, they use the difference in the ratios of the firm with a certain ownership and management structure and the no-agency-cost base case firm. Secondly, following Sign and Davidson (2003), we use the ratio of selling, gene ral and administrative (SG&A) expenses to sales (expense ratio). In contrast to asset turnover, expense ratio is a direct procurator of agency costs.SG&A expenses include salaries, commissions charged by agents to facilitate transactions, travel expenses for executives, advertising and marketing costs, rents and other utilities. Therefore, expense ratio should 11 The asset turnover ratio may also capture (to some extent) agency costs of debt. For instance, the sales ratio provides a good signal for the lender about how effectively the borrower (firm) employs its assets and, therefore, affects the cost of capital 14 reflect to a significant extent managerial discretion in spending company resources.For example, as Sign and Davidson (2003) point out, management may use advertising and selling expenses to camouflage expenditures on perquisites p. 7. Firms with high expense ratios are expected to experience high agency costs between managers and shareholders12. 3. 3 Independent Variabl es Our empirical model includes a set of corporate governance variables related to firms ownership, board, compensation and capital structure. Several control variables are also incorporated. For example, we use the logarithm of total assets in 1999 prices as a proxy for firm size (SIZE).Also, we include the market-to- intelligence value (MKTBOOK) as a proxy for growth opportunities. Finally, we divide firms into 15 sectors and include 14 dummy variables accordingly so as to control for sector specific effects. uninflected definitions for all these variables are given in put back 1. Insert put off 1 here 3. 4 Methodology We examine the determinants of agency costs by employing a cross sectional regression approach. Following Rajan and Zingales (1995) and Ozkan and Ozkan (2004), the dependent variable is measured at some time t, while for the independent variables we use average-past set.Using averages in the way we construct our explanatory variables helps in mitigating potentia l problems that may arise due to short-term fluctuations and extreme values in our data. Also, using past values reduces the likelihood of ascertained relations reflecting the effects of asset turnover on firm specific factors. Specifically, the dependent variable is measured in year 2003. For accounting variables and the market-tobook ratio we use average values for the period 1999-2002. Ownership, board and compensation structure variables are measured in year 2002.Given that equity ownership characteristics in a country are relatively stable over a certain period of time, we do not expect that measuring them in a single year would yield a significant bias in our results (see also La Porta et al. , 2002, among others). 12 An alternative proxy for agency costs between managers and shareholders, which is not used in our paper though, is the interaction of companys growth opportunities with its free cash flow (see Doukas et al. , 2002). 15 Our approach captures potential interaction effects that may be present.For example, as explained analytically in section 2. 6, the nature of the relationship between the alternative governance mechanisms or devices and agency costs may vary with firms growth opportunities. To explore that possibility, we scratchly interact our proxy for growth opportunities (MKTBOOK) with the alternative corporate governance mechanisms. In this way, we test for the existence of both main effects (the impact governance variables on agency costs) and conditional effects (the impact of growth opportunities on the relationship between governance variables and agency costs).Additionally, we split the sample into high-growth and low-growth firms and estimate our empirical models for each sample separately. Then we check whether the coefficients of governance variables retain their sign and their significance across the two sub-samples. 3. 5 Sample Characteristics Table 2 presents descriptive statistics for the main variables used in our analysis . It reveals that the average values of asset turnover ratio and SG&A ratio are 1. 24 and 0. 45 respectively. The mean value for managerial ownership is 14. 4 per cent of which the average proportion of stakes held by executive (non-executive) directors is 10. 68 per cent (4. 06 per cent). The ownership concentration reaches the level of 37. 19 per cent, on average, in the UK firms. Also, the average proportion of non-executive directors is 49. 5 per cent and the average board size consists of 6. 97 directors. Finally, we were able to identify only 73 firms out of the final 897 (8. 1 per cent) in which the same person held the positions of CEO and COB. As far as the capital structure variables are concerned, the average proportion of bank debt on firms capital structure is 55. 5 per cent and that of short-term debt is 49. 53 per cent. Finally, the average market-to-book value is 2. 09. In general, these values are in line with those reported in other studies for UK firms (see, for e xample, Ozkan and Ozkan, 2004 and Short and Keasey, 1999). Insert Table 2 here The results of the Pearsons Correlation of our variables are reported in Table 3. Our inverse proxy for agency costs, asset turnover, is intelligibly positively correlated to managerial ownership, executive ownership, salary, bank debt and short-term debt.Ownership concentration is also positively related to asset turnover but the correlation coefficient is not statistically significant. On the contrary, board size and non-executive 16 directors are arrange to be negatively correlated with asset turnover. Finally, as expected, asset turnover is found to be negatively correlated with both growth opportunities and firm size. The results for our morsel proxy for agency costs, SG&A, are qualitatively similar with a few exceptions (e. g. short-term debt) but with opposite signs given that SG&A is a direct and not an inverse proxy for agency costs. Insert Table 3 here 4. Empirical Results 4. 1 Univariate ana lysis In Table 4 we report univariate mean-comparison test results of the sample firm subgroups categorized on the basis of to a higher place and below median values for managerial ownership, ownership concentration, board size, proportion of non-executives, bank debt, short-term debt, total debt, salary, firm size and growth opportunities. Firms with above median managerial ownership (ownership concentration) have asset turnover of 1. 34 (1. 31) whereas those with below median managerial ownership (ownership concentration) have asset turnover of 1. 5 (1. 17). These differences are statistically significant at the 1 per cent (5 per cent) level. The results for executive ownership, salary, bank debt and short-term debt are also found to be statistically significant and are in the hypothesized direction. Specifically, we find that firms with above median values for all the above mentioned variables have relatively higher asset utilization ratios. On the contrary, there is evidence th at firms with larger board sizes indicate significantly lower asset utilization ratios. Insert Table 4 here In panel B of the same table we report the results using SG&A expense ratio as a proxy for agency costs. Results are in general not in line with the hypothesized signs with notable exceptions those of ownership concentration and growth opportunities. For example, firms with above median ownership concentration (MKTBOOK) have an SG&A expense ratio of 0. 41 (0. 55) whereas firms with below median ownership concentration (MKTBOOK) have an SG&A expense ratio of 0. 49 (0. 36).However, the results for managerial ownership, salary and short-term debt suggest that these governance mechanisms or devices are not effective in protecting firms from excessive SG&A 17 expenses. Sign and Davidson (2003) obtains a set of similar results, for the case when agency costs are approximated with the SG&A ratio. Overall, the univariate analysis indicates several corporate governance mechanisms or de vices, such as managerial ownership, ownership concentration, salary, bank debt and short-term debt, which can help mitigate agency problems between managers and shareholders.Also, consistent with previous studies, we find that the relation between governance variables and agency costs is stronger for the asset turnover ratio than the SG&A expense ratio. The analysis that follows allows us to test the validity of these results in a multivariate framework. 4. 2 Multivariate analysis In this section we present our results that are based on a cross sectional regression approach. We start with a linear specification model, where we include only total debt from our set of capital structure variables (model 1).In general, the estimated coefficients are in line with the hypothesized signs. Specifically, consistent with the results of Ang et al. (2000) and Sign and Davidson (2003), we find both managerial ownership and ownership concentration to be positively related to asset-turnover. The coefficients are statistically significant at the 5 per cent and 1 per cent significance level respectively. On the contrary, the coefficient for board size is negative, which probably indicates that firms with larger board size are less efficient in their asset utilization.Also, the results for our proxy for growth opportunities (MKTBOOK) support the view that high-growth firms suffer from higher agency costs than low-growth firms. Finally, there is strong evidence that managerial salary can work as an effective incentive mechanism that helps aligning the interests of managers with those of shareholders. Specifically, the coefficient for salary is positive and statistically significant to the 1 per cent level. Therefore, compared to previous studies, our empirical model provides evidence on the existence of an additive potential corporate governance mechanism available to firms. Insert Table 5 here In model 2 we incorporate two supererogatory capital structure variables, the rat io of bank debt to total debt and the ratio of short-term debt to total debt, in order to test whether debtsource and debt-maturity impacts agency costs. Also, we split managerial ownership into executive ownership (the amount of shares held by executive directors) and non-executive 18 ownership (the amount of shares held by non-executive directors). We do this because we expect that equity ownership works as a better incentive mechanism in the hands of executive directors rather in the hands of non-executive directors.According to our results, bank debt is positively related to asset turnover. Also, in addition to debt source, the maturity structure of debt seems to have a significant effect on agency costs. The coefficient of short-term debt is positive and statistically significant at the 1 per cent significance level. Furthermore, there is evidence that from total managerial ownership, only the amount of shares held by executive directors can enhance asset utilization and, hence , align the interest of managers with those of shareholders.In model 3 we estimate a non-linear model by adding the square of salary. As explained earlier in the paper, a priori expectations, which are supported by preliminary graphical investigation, suggest that the relationship between asset turnover and salary can be non-monotonic. Our results provide strong evidence that the relationship between salary and asset turnover is non-linear. In particular, at low levels of salary, the relationship between salary and asset turnover is positive. However, at higher levels of salary, the relationship becomes negative.This result is consistent with studies that suggest that super high levels of salary usually work as an infectious greed and create agency conflicts between managers and shareholders. The coefficients of the remaining variables are similar to those reported in models 1 and 2. Finally, in model 4 we allow for a non-linear relationship between executive ownership and agency c osts. However, our results do not support such a relationship and, therefore, the square term in our following models13.To sum up, the results of Table 5 indicate that managerial ownership (executive ownership), ownership concentration, salary (when it is at low levels), bank debt and short-term debt can help in mitigating agency problems by enhancing asset utilization. Also, the coefficients for the control variables market to book and firm size, negative and positive respectively, suggest that smaller and non- growth firms are associated with cut down asset utilization ratio and, hence, more severe agency problems between managers and shareholders.As discussed earlier in the paper, there is a possibility that the nature of the relationship between the alternative governance mechanisms or devices and agency costs varies with firms growth opportunities. In dialog box A of Table 6, we explore such a In trial regressions, which are not reported, the third-dimensional term of executi ve ownership is also included in our model. Once more, the results do not support the existence of a non-monotonic relationship. 13 19 possibility by interacting those governance mechanisms found significant in models 1-4 with growth opportunities, proxied by market-to-book ratio.Our empirical results support the existence of two interaction effects. We find that executive ownership is an effective governance mechanism especially for high-growth firms (the coefficient EXECOWNER* MKTBOOK is positive and statistically significant). This result is consistent with the study of Lasfer (2002), which suggests that the positive relationship between managerial ownership and firm value is stronger in high-growth firms. On the contrary, the coefficient SHORT_DEBT*MKTBOOK is found to be negative and statistically significant.This means that the efficiency of short-term debt in mitigating agency problems is lower for high-growth firms. A possible explanation may be that short-term debt basically mitigates agency problems related to free cash flow. Given that high-growth firms do not suffer from severe free cash-flow problems (but mainly from asymmetric information problems), the efficiency of short-term debt as governance device decreases for these firms. One could argue, though, that short-term debt should be more important for the case of highgrowth firms since it helps reduce underinvestment problems.However, it seems that this effect is not very strong for the case in our sample. A similar result is obtained in McConnell and Servaes (1995) who find that the relationship between corporate value and leverage is positive (negative) for low-growth (high-growth) firms14. Insert Table 6 here Secondly, we use the variable MKTBOOK so as two split the sample into two subsamples. We label the upper 45 per cent in terms of MKTBOOK as high-growth firms and the lower 45 per cent as low-growth firms. Then, we re-estimate our basic model for the two sub-samples separately (Table 6, p anel B).The results of this exercise confirm the existence of an interaction effect between executive ownership and asset turnover. In particular, the coefficient of EXECOWNER is positive and statistically significant only in the case of the sample that includes only high-growth firms. As far as short-term debt is concerned, it is found to be positive and statistically significant in both samples. 14 The idea in McConnell and Servaes (1995) is that debt has both a positive and a negative impact on the value of the firm because of its influence on corporate investment decisions.What possibly happens is that the negative effect of debt dominates the positive effect in firms with more positive net present value projects (i. e. , high-growth firms) and that the positive effect will dominate the negative effect for firms with fewer positive net present value projects (i. e. , low-growth firms). 20 To summarize, the results of our multivariate analysis suggest, among others, that executiv e ownership and ownership concentration can work as effective governance mechanisms for the case of the UK market.These results are in line with the ones reported by the studies Ang et al. (2000) and sign and Davidson (2003). Also, we find that, in addition to the source of debt, the maturity structure of debt can help to reduce agency conflicts between managers and shareholders. The fact that previous studies have ignored the maturity structure of debt may partly explain their contradicting results concerning the relationship between capital structure and agency costs. Furthermore, we find that salary can work as an additional mechanism that provides incentives to managers to take valuemaximizing actions.However, its impact on asset turnover is not always positive i. e. the relationship between asset turnover and salary is non-monotonic. Finally, there is strong evidence that the relationship between several governance mechanisms and agency costs varies with growth opportunities. S pecifically, our results support the view that the positive relationship between executive ownership (short-term debt) is stronger for the case of high growth (low growth) firms. 4. Robustness checks Given the significant impact of growth opportunities on agency costs (main impact) and on the impact of other corporate governance mechanisms (conditional impact), we further investigate the relationship between growth opportunities, governance mechanisms and agency costs. At first, we substitute the variable MKTBOOK with an alternative proxy for growth opportunities. The new proxy is derived after employing common factor analysis, a statistical technique that uses the correlations between observed variables to estimate common factors and the structural relationships linking factors to observed variables.The variables which are used in order to isolate latent factors that account for the patterns of colinearity are following variables MKTBOOK = Book value of total assets minus the book value of equity plus the market value of equity to book value of assets MTBE = Market value of equity to book value of equity METBA = Market value of equity to the book value of assets METD = Market value of equity plus the book value of debt to the book value of assets. 21 These variables have been extensively used in the literature as alternative proxies for growth opportunities and Tobins Q.As shown in Table 7 (panel A) all these variables are highly correlated to each other. In order to make sure that principal component analysis can provide valid results for the case of our sample, we perform two tests in our sample, the Barletts test and the Kaiser-Meyer-Olkin test. The first test examines whether or not the intercorrelation matrix comes from a population in which the variables are noncollinear (i. e. an identity matrix). The second test is a test for sampling adequacy.The results from these tests, which are reported in panel B, are encourage and suggest that common factor an alysis can be employed in our sample since all the four proxies are likely to measure the same thing i. e. growth opportunities. Panel C presents the eigenvalues of the reduced correlation matrix of our four proxies for growth opportunities. Each factor whose eigenvalue is greater than 1 explains more variance than a single variable. Given that only one eigenvalue is greater than 1, our common factor analysis provides us with one factor that can explain firm growth opportunities.Clearly, as shown in panel D, the factor is highly correlated with all MKTBOOK, MTBE, METBA and METD. We name the new variable produce and use it as an alternative proxy for growth opportunities. Descriptive statistics for the variable GROWTH are presented in panel D. Insert Table 7 here Table 8 presents the results of cross-section analysis after using the variable GROWTH as proxy for agency costs. In general, the results of such a task are similar to the ones reported previously.For instance, there is str ong evidence that executive ownership, ownership concentration, salary, short-term debt and, to some extent, bank debt are positively related to asset turnover. Also, there is some evidence supporting a non-linear relationship between salary and asset turnover. Finally, our results clearly indicate that agency costs differ significantly across high-growth and low-growth firms and, most importantly, there is a significant interaction effect between growth opportunities and executive ownership.However, we can not provide any evidence on the existence of an interaction between asset turnover and short-term debt. Insert Table 8 here 22 In panel B of table 8, we split our sample into high-growth and low-growth firms on the basis of high and low values for the variable GROWTH. Specifically, we label the upper 45 per cent in terms of GROWTH as high-growth firms and the lower 45 per cent as low-growth firms. Then we estimate our basic model for each sub-sample separately. The results are ve ry similar to the ones reported in Table 6 (panel B), where we apply a similar methodology.As an additional robustness check, we use a third proxy for growth opportunities, a dummy variable that takes the value of 1 if the firm is a high-growth firm and 0 otherwise, and re-estimate the models 6 and 7 of Table 8. The definition used in order to distinguish between high-growth and low-growth firms is the following Firms above the 55th percentile in terms of the variable GROWTH are called high-growth firms. Firms below the 45th percentile in terms of the variable GROWTH are called low-growth firms.Finally, firms between the 45th and 55th percentile are excluded from the sample. The results (not reported) are qualitatively similar to the ones reported in Table 8. For example, there is evidence for the existence of an interaction effect between executive ownership and growth opportunities but not for the one between short-term debt and growth opportunities. Also, we re-estimate the model s reported in Table 8 after substituting the total salary paid to executive directors for the total remuneration package paid to executive directors.We are doing so given that the total remuneration package that is paid to managers includes several other components. For instance, the components of compensation structure have been increased in number during the last decade and may include annual performance bonus, fringe benefits, stock (e. g. preference shares), stock options, stock appreciation rights, apparition shares and other deferred compensation mechanisms like qualified retirement plans (see Lynch and Perry, 2003 for an analytical discussion). Once more, the results do not change substantially.Finally, in Table 9 we substitute the annual sales to total assets with the ratio of SG&A expenses to total sales. As already mentioned earlier in the paper, this ratio can be used as a direct proxy for agency costs. Our results, as presented in Table 9, indicate that executive owners hip, ownership concentration and total debt help reduce discretionary spending and, therefore, the agency conflicts between managers and shareholders. Sign and Davidson (2003) do not find any evidence to support these results. Also, we find that agency costs and growth opportunities are positively related i. . the coefficient of the variable GROWTH is positive and statistically significant to the 5 per cent statistical level. 23 Finally, our results support the existence of an interaction effect between growth opportunities and executive ownership. However, once more, our analysis does not indicate the existence of an interaction effect between short-term debt and growth opportunities. Insert Table 9 here 5. Conclusion In this paper we have examined the effectiveness of the alternative corporate governance mechanisms and devices in mitigating managerial agency problems in the UK market.In particular, we have investigated the impact of capital structure, corporate ownership structure , board structure and managerial compensation structure on the costs arising from agency conflicts mainly between managers and shareholders. The interactions among them and growth opportunities in determining the magnitude of these conflicts have also been tested. Our results strongly suggest managerial ownership, ownership concentration, executive compensation, short-term debt and, to some extent, bank debt are important governance mechanisms for the UK companies.Moreover, growth opportunities is a significant determinant of the magnitude of agency costs. Our results suggest that highgrowth firms face more serious agency problems than low-growth firms, possibly because of information asymmetries between managers, shareholders and debtholders. Finally, there is strong evidence that some governance mechanisms are not homogeneous but vary with growth oppo

No comments:

Post a Comment

Note: Only a member of this blog may post a comment.